Provision of Care: A Challenge for Economics

Provision of Care: A Challenge for Economics

Provision of Care: A Challenge for Economics

The size of an economy is typically measured by Gross Domestic Product, which sums up all the monetary transactions in an economy.

Non-monetary actions like household production are not covered by GDP: to use the old classroom example, if two stay-at-home parents hired each other to do all the household tasks, then GDP would go up, but if they work in their own homes, GDP is lower. Government statisticians have estimated that if the value of household production was included in GDP, the size of the US economy would be about one-fifth bigger.

But of course, household production feeds back into the monetary transactions part of the economy in many ways. Raising children today will help make Social Security solvent a few decades from now. Providing care to someone with a disability or recovering from illness can help them enter or re-enter the workforce. In a number of paid jobs, like teachers and health care workers, some employees will provide a quality of care far higher than others, without receiving monetary compensation for the higher lifetime earnings of students or the quicker return to health of patients.

Nancy Folbre tackles many of these issues in “Care Provision and the Boundaries of Production,” in the Winter 2024 issue of the Journal of Economic Perspectives. (Full disclosure: I’ve been the Managing Editor of JEP since 1986, and so may be predisposed to find the articles published there of interest. Since 2011, all articles published in JEP, including all archives back to the first issue, have been freely available online courtesy of the publisher, the American Economic Association.)

As Folbre emphasizes, neither the costs of care nor the broader benefits of care are well-captured by a focus on monetary transactions. I can’t do justice to the full argument here, but here are a couple of comments to ponder.

As Folbre points out, we socialize the economic benefits of children through programs like Social Security and more generally through taxes paid by future workers, but we rely heavily on nonmonetary private provision of care for raising children. She writes:

The US Social Security system taxes employees to finance health and retirement benefits for retirees. These benefits, linked to the earnings history of recipients and their spouses, offer no credit for the time and money put into raising future taxpayers. As a result, the net benefits of Social Security are significantly higher for individuals who devote relatively little time or money to children, even though single-earner married couples reap higher net benefits than dual-earner or single-parent households. US public policies socialize the economic benefits of children far more extensively than the costs (Folbre and Wolf 2013). Parents—defined in terms of contribution to childrearing rather than biology—create a significant fiscal externality by raising the next generation of taxpayers (Wolf et al. 2011). While empirical research has not yet distinguished between the total contributions of mothers and fathers or impact of greater life expectancy (and thus greater take-up of Social Security and Medicare) among women, mothers clearly make larger fiscal contributions through this channel than either childless individuals or noncustodial parents who fail to provide much support for their biological children.

Folbre on the role of care provided by teachers:

However, teachers are obviously not rewarded for their individual contributions to their students’ lifetime skills, just as parents are not rewarded for their value added to their children. Likewise, nurses and doctors are not rewarded for their individual contributions to patients’ lifetime health, and social workers are not rewarded for their individual contributions to social welfare. Industry wage differentials’ net of personal characteristics partly reflect cross-industry differences in ability to capture value-added: Unlike employees in care services, employees in business services generate measurable and significant revenues for their employers, are more easily paid for performance, and earn significantly more …

Folbre on the arguments about the subjective satisfaction of care to providers, rather than recognizing the social gains from such care.

Rather than treating care provision merely as a source of subjective satisfaction, we could recognize its moral valence and productive contributions. Rather than valuing human capital as an input into market output, we could value market output as an input into the improvement of human capabilities. Rather than fighting over the distribution of costs and benefits, we could emphasize the gains from well-designed social insurance programs. We cannot accomplish these goals without expanding the boundaries of production to look inside households and beyond market dynamics. Concerns about the negative consequences of inadequate care provision in the United States are growing. As one example, a coalition of large corporations, small businesses, entrepreneurs, and investors formed a Care Economy Business Council in 2021 (https://timesupnow.org/care-economy-business-council) to “shift the cultural narrative about who is responsible for care, encourage and enforce equitable practices to support caregivers, and advocate for key public policy interventions.”

Share this article

Leave your comments

Post comment as a guest

0
terms and condition.
  • No comments found

Share this article

Timothy Taylor

Global Economy Expert

Timothy Taylor is an American economist. He is managing editor of the Journal of Economic Perspectives, a quarterly academic journal produced at Macalester College and published by the American Economic Association. Taylor received his Bachelor of Arts degree from Haverford College and a master's degree in economics from Stanford University. At Stanford, he was winner of the award for excellent teaching in a large class (more than 30 students) given by the Associated Students of Stanford University. At Minnesota, he was named a Distinguished Lecturer by the Department of Economics and voted Teacher of the Year by the master's degree students at the Hubert H. Humphrey Institute of Public Affairs. Taylor has been a guest speaker for groups of teachers of high school economics, visiting diplomats from eastern Europe, talk-radio shows, and community groups. From 1989 to 1997, Professor Taylor wrote an economics opinion column for the San Jose Mercury-News. He has published multiple lectures on economics through The Teaching Company. With Rudolph Penner and Isabel Sawhill, he is co-author of Updating America's Social Contract (2000), whose first chapter provided an early radical centrist perspective, "An Agenda for the Radical Middle". Taylor is also the author of The Instant Economist: Everything You Need to Know About How the Economy Works, published by the Penguin Group in 2012. The fourth edition of Taylor's Principles of Economics textbook was published by Textbook Media in 2017.

   
Save
Cookies user prefences
We use cookies to ensure you to get the best experience on our website. If you decline the use of cookies, this website may not function as expected.
Accept all
Decline all
Read more
Analytics
Tools used to analyze the data to measure the effectiveness of a website and to understand how it works.
Google Analytics
Accept
Decline